Missouri's Certificate-of-Need Program: Lessons from Research

Missouri Senate Committee on Health and Pensions

Chair Onder, Vice Chair Koenig, and members of the Senate Committee on Health and Pensions:

My name is Matthew Mitchell. I am an economist at the Mercatus Center at George Mason University. In recent years, my colleagues and I have been studying certificate-of-need (CON) laws in healthcare. I am grateful for the opportunity to discuss our findings with you today.

Today, I will

  1. offer a brief history of CON laws,
  2. compare Missouri’s CON program to the programs in other states,
  3. give an overview of the economic evidence that supports the conclusion that these laws harm patients and taxpayers, and
  4. suggest reforms, including outright repeal, that would improve both patient and overall welfare in the state.

Introduction to CON Laws

CON laws require healthcare providers wishing to open or expand a healthcare facility to first prove to a regulatory body that their community needs the services the facility would provide. The regulations are typically not designed to assess a provider’s qualifications or safety record. Other regulations such as occupational licensing aim to do that. Instead, CON laws aim to determine whether or not a service is economically viable and valuable.

The process for obtaining a CON can sometimes take years and cost tens or even hundreds of thousands of dollars in preparation costs. These regulations appear to benefit incumbent providers by limiting their competition; their effects on patients and taxpayers, however, have generally been found to be negative. This finding helps explain why antitrust authorities at the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) and at the US Department of Justice (DOJ) have long taken the position that these rules are anticompetitive. In a joint report from 2004, for example, the FTC and DOJ declared,

"The Agencies believe that, on balance, CON programs are not successful in containing health care costs, and that they pose serious anticompetitive risks that usually outweigh their purported economic benefits."

A Brief History of CON Regulation

Almost five decades ago, Congress passed and President Ford signed the National Health Planning and Resources Development Act of 1974. The statute enabled the federal government to withhold federal funds from states that failed to adopt CON regulations in healthcare.

New York had already enacted the first CON program in 1964; by the early 1980s, with the federal government’s encouragement, every state except Louisiana had implemented some version of a CON program. Policymakers hoped that these programs would restrain healthcare costs, increase healthcare quality, and improve access to care for poor and underserved communities.

In 1986—after Medicare changed its reimbursement practices and as evidence mounted that CON laws were failing to achieve their stated goals—Congress repealed the federal statute, eliminating federal incentives for states to maintain their CON programs. Since then, 15 states, representing about 40 percent of the US population, have done away with their CON regulations, and many have pared them back. A majority of states still maintain CON programs, however, and vestiges of the National Health Planning and Resources Development Act can be seen in the justifications that state legislatures offer in support of these regulations.

CON Regulation in Missouri

Missouri operates an extensive CON program, requiring providers to obtain permission before making changes to equipment, services, facilities, hospital beds, and nonhospital beds. Missouri’s CON application fee is $1,000 or 0.1 percent of the total cost of the proposed project, whichever is greater.

Table 1 shows the number of technologies and procedures regulated by Missouri and by the surrounding states. Among all states with CON regulations, the average number of regulated technologies and procedures is 15. Missouri regulates 18 technologies and procedures.

The state requires CONs for services that are unlikely to be overprescribed, such as obstetrics services and neonatal intensive care. The state also requires CONs for facilities and types of care that often go to vulnerable populations, such as intermediate care facilities for those with intellectual disabilities, psychiatric care, and substance abuse services. Some of the regulated services can be provided without expensive capital investments (psychiatric are, for example). The following services and technologies are regulated under Missouri’s CON program:

  • Assisted living and residential care facilities
  • Cardiac catheterization
  • Computed tomography (CT) scanners
  • Gamma knives
  • Hospital beds
  • Intermediate care facilities (ICFs) for individuals with intellectual disabilities
  • Linear accelerator radiology
  • Lithotripsy
  • Long-term acute care (LTAC)
  • Magnetic-resonance imaging (MRI) scanners
  • Mobile HI technology (CT/MRI/PET, etc.)
  • New hospitals or hospital-sized investments
  • Nursing home beds/long-term care beds
  • Obstetrics services
  • Positron emission tomography (PET) scanners
  • Psychiatric services
  • Rehabilitation
  • Substance/drug abuse

The Economics of CON Regulation

Unfortunately, by limiting supply and undermining competition, CON programs may undercut each of the laudable aims that policymakers desire to achieve with these rules. In fact, research shows that CON laws fail to achieve the goals most often given when enacting such laws. These goals include

  1. ensuring an adequate supply of healthcare resources,
  2. ensuring access to healthcare for rural communities,
  3. promoting high-quality healthcare,
  4. ensuring charity care for those unable to pay or for otherwise underserved communities,
  5. encouraging appropriate levels of hospital substitutes and healthcare alternatives, and
  6. restraining the cost of healthcare services.

Researchers have ample information to help predict what would happen if Missouri were to repeal its CON regulations because 15 states have repealed their CON programs, and others have pared theirs back. Economists have used modern statistical methods to compare outcomes in CON and non-CON states to estimate the effects of these regulations. These methods control for factors such as socioeconomic conditions that might confound the estimates. Table 2 summarizes some of this research. It is organized around the stated goals of CON laws.

Using the experiences of other states, one can estimate what fiscal and health outcomes are likely to prevail in a Missouri without CON regulation. These estimates are derived from cross-state regression analyses that track outcomes over decades. They account for socioeconomic differences as well as differences in the underlying health of the state populations.

Figure 1 shows the actual number of hospitals as well as the estimated number of hospitals in a Missouri without CON regulation.

Missouri’s rural hospitals are financially strained, so the effect of CON regulation on rural care is especially important to the state’s rural communities. Figure 2 shows the number of rural hospitals in Missouri and estimates of how many there would be in a Missouri without CON regulation.

Figure 3 shows the actual as well as the estimated mortality rates following heart attack, heart failure, and pneumonia.

Figure 4 shows the actual as well as estimated readmission rates following heart attack and heart failure.

In addition, researchers estimate that postsurgery complications would be approximately 5.8 percent lower and that the share of patients rating their hospital experience a 9 out of 10 or 10 out of 10 would be approximately 4.6 percent higher in a Missouri without CON regulation. Finally, economists estimate that annual per capita healthcare spending would be approximately $238 lower in a Missouri without CON regulation.

Reform Options

The weight of evidence suggests that a full repeal of CON laws would expand access to healthcare in Missouri that is of both high quality and low cost. Repeal might be scheduled to take effect in the near future or at a later date. Alternatively, policymakers might phase in repeal by requiring the CON board to approve an ever-larger percentage of applications over a certain number of years.

Short of full repeal, policymakers have a number of options to reform the program and limit its negative effects. For example, the state might eliminate specific CON requirements. Some requirements ripe for reform include

  1. CONs that restrict access to facilities and services used by vulnerable populations, such as intermediate care facilities for those with intellectual disabilities, psychiatric services, and substance abuse services;
  2. CONs for services that are unlikely to be overprescribed, such as obstetrics service and neonatal intensive care; and
  3. CONs for services that require limited capital expenditures, such as rehabilitation.

Policymakers might also consider a number of options to ease the administrative burden of CON laws. For example, they might reduce Missouri’s fees, reduce the administrative burden of the application process, or require incumbents who unsuccessfully challenge an entrant’s CON application to pay the entrant’s legal and compliance costs.

The criteria used to evaluate a CON application might also be changed. For example, a CON application should not be rejected to prevent the provision of duplicative services. Such a rejection would guarantee monopoly status for the current service providers, and healthcare monopolies are associated with high-cost, low-quality care. Utilization rate is another poor criterion. If an existing hospital knows that potential competitors are less likely to obtain CONs if it keeps its bed utilization rate low, then it faces an incentive to acquire more beds than it needs and ensure that many of them remain empty. This is exactly the sort of unnecessary capital expenditure that CON regulation was supposed to discourage.

In addition, the state might raise the monetary threshold of an investment that necessitates a CON or apply this threshold to medical equipment. It might also require the CON board to seek input from parties without financial interest in the outcome or from parties dedicated to the preservation of market competition, such as patient health advocates, economists, or antitrust authorities at the FTC.

Finally, policymakers might consider a number of options that would increase the transparency of the CON program and make legislative oversight easier. One option would be to require the board to regularly disclose the CON approval rate. The board could also be required to report the share of applications opposed by incumbent providers as well as the different approval rates for opposed and unopposed applications. The board could be required to ask applicants to estimate their costs of applying for a CON and then regularly report these numbers to the public. And finally, the board could be required to follow up with denied applicants to evaluate how the denial has affected their provision of services.

Concluding Remarks

Given the substantial evidence that CON laws do not achieve their stated goals, one may wonder why these laws continue to exist in so much of the country. The explanation seems to lie in the special-interest theory of regulation. Specifically, CON laws perform a valuable function for incumbent providers of healthcare services by limiting their exposure to new competition. Indeed, recent evidence suggests that special interest groups are able to use political donations to increase the odds that their CON requests will be granted. This aspect of CON regulation is one reason why economists as well as antitrust authorities have long believed that these regulations are anticompetitive and harmful to consumers.

For those who are interested in further details on the effects of CON laws on spending patterns, I have attached my paper, “Do Certificate-of-Need Laws Limit Spending?” Like all Mercatus Center research, it has been through a rigorous, double-blind peer review process.

Thank you again for the opportunity to share my research with you. I look forward to answering any questions you may have.

Attachment

Do Certificate-of-Need Laws Limit Spending?” (Mercatus Working Paper)